Algeria
Angola
Benin
Botswana
Burkina Faso
Burundi
Cameroon
Cape Verde
Central Afr. Rep.
Chad
Comoros
Congo (Brazzaville)
Congo (Kinshasa)
Cτte d'Ivoire
Djibouti
Egypt
Equatorial Guinea
Eritrea
Ethiopia
Gabon
Gambia
Ghana
Guinea
Guinea-Bissau
Kenya
Lesotho
Liberia
Libya
Madagascar
Malawi
Mali
Mauritania
Mauritius
Morocco
Mozambique
Namibia
Niger
Nigeria
Rwanda
São Tomé
Senegal
Seychelles
Sierra Leone
Somalia
South Africa
South Sudan
Sudan
Swaziland
Tanzania
Togo
Tunisia
Uganda
Western Sahara
Zambia
Zimbabwe
|
Get AfricaFocus Bulletin by e-mail!
on your Newsreader!
Format for print or mobile
Africa: Carbon Trading Deceptions
AfricaFocus Bulletin
Dec 7, 2011 (111207)
(Reposted from sources cited below)
Editor's Note
"Africa's share has remained at about two per cent of CDM
(Clean Development Mechanism) projects officially registered
with the UN's climate change secretariat. If South Africa
and countries in North Africa are taken out of the
aggregate, all the other African countries currently account
for just 0.6 per cent of registered CDM projects." But even
in carbon markets in Africa were expanded, argues this new
comprehensive study from the Institute for Strategic
Studies, carbon offsets at best bring only deceptive
benefits to developing countries, while allowing rich
countries to evade their responsibilities for reducing
carbon emissions.
The report, entitled Carbon Trading in Africa: A Critical
Review, and edited by Trisha Reddy, was released in
November. In addition to three overview chapters and
concluding recommendations, it contains detailed summaries
of existing offset projects in South Africa, Uganda, and
Ethiopia; a chapter on the World Bank and forest projects in
Africa; and an incisive critique of the inherent flaws in
carbon offset markets, noting their "un-regulatable
chactacter" similar to that of the financial derivatives
markets. The result, notes leading expert Larry Lohmann in
that chapter, is "regulation as corruption," in which those
presenting carbon offset projects essentially make up
plausible but unverifiable scenarios comparing the carbon
impact of projects with the counterfactual scenario of the
project not happening.
The full report, a fundamental resource on the subject, is
available as a pdf download at http://www.iss.co.za/pgcontent.php?UID=31241
This Bulletin, available on the web at http://www.africafocus.org/docs11/clim1112b.php but not sent
out by e-mail, contains the text of Chapter 2, with an
overview of carbon trading in Africa to date as well as a
review of pending projects.
Another AfricaFocus Bulletin with several recent documents
on climate change is being sent out today by e-mail and is
also available on the web at http://www.africafocus.org/docs11/clim1112a.php
For previous AfricaFocus Bulletins on climate change and the
environment, visit http://www.africafocus.org/envexp.php
For an earlier report on carbon trading as a false solution,
see http://www.africafocus.org/docs10/can1012b.php
++++++++++++++++++++++end editor's note+++++++++++++++++
Climate change and carbon trading in Africa
Yacob Mulugetta
in Trisha Reddy, ed., Carbon Trading in Africa: A Critical
Review. Institute for Security Studies Monograph 184,
November 2011
[Note: chapter text only. Notes for chapter available in pdf
at: http://www.iss.co.za/pgcontent.php?UID=31241]
Introduction
Africa has gained few benefits from economic globalisation,
and the continent's economies continue to depend on a
handful of primary goods whose prices are determined
externally. This unjust allocation of resources, access, and
development extends to climate policies in that Africa's
interests have remained peripheral to their implementation.
The introduction of carbon trading schemes has arguably not
transferred finance or technology to Africa. Just two per
cent of projects under the Clean Development Mechanism
(CDM), the main carbon market resulting from the Kyoto
Protocol, are in Africa, and if South Africa is excluded, a
mere 0.6 per cent of these are in sub-Saharan Africa. With
carbon markets driven primarily by commercial interests,
most CDM credits are awarded for simple changes to reduce
industrial gases other than CO2. The manufacturing
facilities that generate these gases are not found in
Africa. While hydro power, the other major source of CDM
credits to date, is the most common form of electricity
generation in sub-Saharan Africa, this results in an
assumption that the energy mix is already clean. Simply put,
sub-Saharan African countries are not deemed to be dirty
enough, or to consume enough, to compete successfully for
CDM projects.
Partly in response to these failures, CDM reform is being
discussed at UN climate negotiations. However, the
approaches favoured in these talks could exacerbate rather
than ameliorate the problems associated with carbon trading.
One of the main proposals is to replace a project-based
approach with one that encompasses entire economic sectors.
However, this does not solve the basic problem of carbon
'offsetting', namely its lack of environmental and social
integrity. Nor would a sectoral approach address the
geographic imbalance in favour of middle-income countries. A
second scheme that is heavily linked to carbon markets is
Reducing Emissions from Degradation and Deforestation
(REDD). However, this could introduce a series of additional
problems, including the displacement of forest-based
communities, and a financial incentive to replace complex
forest ecosystems with monoculture plantations. Serious
doubts also remain about the ability to account for
emissions 'savings' from REDD. Thus far, the evidence shows
that carbon trading is an ineffective way of addressing
climate change, largely helping powerful governments and
business executives to meet the demands for action on
climate change while preserving the commercial and
geopolitical status quo.
This chapter probes these issues by placing climate change
in its historical and political context. This may help us to
understand why and how carbon trading falls short of
addressing carbon mitigation efforts, and limiting the
effect of climate change on livelihoods in Africa. It then
discusses the marginalisation of Africa in the carbon
market. Finally, it explores some future trends in the
African carbon market.
The historical and political context of climate change
The historical legacy of unequal access to resources and
unequal development demands an open debate about the causes
of anthropogenic greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions, how past
and future emissions are likely to be allocated, and what
interventions are required to engage in a meaningful way
with CO2 stabilisation efforts. Placing the climate
discussion in its historical (and political) context has two
important functions. Firstly, it helps us to appreciate the
origins of the problem and the possible effects of global
warming on present and future generations, thus situating
local impacts firmly in global politics and economics, and
helping us to discuss inequality in a concrete way.
Secondly, it helps us to explain the evolution of social and
environmental systems while explicitly considering relations
of power, thus providing a platform for challenging dominant
accounts of environmental change.1 The argument here is that
environmental change and ecological conditions are
fundamentally linked to broader economic, social and
political processes in which the 'triple inequality'2 of
vulnerability, responsibility, and mitigation are embedded.
It is worth focusing on 'responsibility', given that an
agreement in this area would constitute a first step towards
arriving at 'fair' solutions. The advocates of industrial
progress saw nature as a source of unlimited resources to
sustain development, with an infinite reservoir for waste.
This extractionâdumping paradigm involves a highly unequal
sharing of the benefits of material and energy flows on one
hand, and the social and environmental costs incurred at all
stages of the commodity chain on the other. The negative
impacts are often absorbed by upstream communities, mainly
involved in resource extraction, which are almost always
rural, poor, and powerless. Byrne et al3 argue that the
industrialised world consumes a disproportionate part of
global resources via supply systems that extract energy from
various parts of the world. The US alone consumes a quarter
of the world's energy, while its share of global Gross
Domestic Product (GDP) is 22 per cent, and its share of the
world population only 5 per cent. At the opposite end of the
spectrum, less than one-fifth of global resources are
dedicated to the needs of the South, home to two-thirds of
the human community.
Of course, consumption at the individual level cannot be
divorced from the wider project of economic growth and
accumulation that governments have pursued so relentlessly,
particularly over the past three decades of neoliberal
ascendancy.4 Moreover, in the course of pursuing economic
growth, some progress has been made in the efficient use of
resources for each unit of economic activity.5 For example,
energy intensity in both the UK and US is about 40 per cent
lower than in 1980,6 as are material intensities more
generally. A possible motive is that the 'redesign' of goods
and services can help an economy to grow without depleting
resources and surpassing ecological limits.
However, this harbours a paradox. Despite declining energy
and carbon intensities, carbon dioxide emissions are almost
40 per cent higher than they were in 1990, which the Kyoto
Protocol treats as the baseline for calculating changes in
GHG emissions. The simple explanation for this lies in the
sheer size of the global economy, which has grown more than
five times since the mid-20th century, and could be 15 times
larger than it is today by 2050.7 These figures also reflect
high levels of consumption in industrialised countries, with
an expanding range of consumer goods and services8 also
becoming increasingly accessible to populations in emerging
economies. This phenomenon is threatening to wreck the very
ecosystems that sustain the global economy and the
livelihoods of billions of people.
Given the strong relationship between economic growth and
consumption, it is difficult to see a way out of this
impasse in the absence of a hegemonic project that can
challenge and reverse neoliberal policies.
What we have seen over the past 30 years is a remarkable
shift in power from producer to consumer at almost every
point along the commodity chain. The global integration of
production and consumption has resulted in a major shift in
the ecological load from North to South over the past 20
years. Thus the Netherlands Environmental Assessment Agency
reports that China has overtaken the US as the biggest CO2
emitter, although its per capita emissions are still a
quarter of those in the US, and half of those in the UK.9
On closer examination, the picture is even more complex.10 A
study by the New Economic Foundation (NEF)11 shows that
large proportions of China's rising emissions are due to the
dependence of the rest of the world on exports from that
country. Thus growing demand for cheap consumer products is
turning China into the environmental or 'carbon' laundry for
the Western world. The NEF report also points to the
relocation of significant numbers of heavy (energyintensive)
industries to China as a visible outcome of
policies of market deregulation and free trade. Since
China's energy mix is more fossil-fuel-intensive than those
of Europe, Japan or the US, outsourcing to China from
'apparently cleaner, richer nations' creates more
'greenhouse gas emissions for each product made'.12
The intention here is not to defend China in respect of
climate change. The evidence shows quite clearly that
China's industries and power stations are playing a major
role in rising GHG emissions. Instead, this discussion is
aimed at placing the ecological implications of global trade
underpinned by neoliberalism in perspective, and challenging
the myth that the self-regulating market is the best
possible mechanism for addressing the world's problems,
including climate change and poverty. The concerted effort
to subordinate society to the logic of the market in such a
way that 'social relations are embedded in the economic
system' has created unexpected contradictions.13 The very
act of subordinating natural and social systems to the
market has unleashed new problems, some of which will have
profound consequences for human society and the biological
world as a whole.
The altered chemistry of the planet's atmosphere presents
industrial society with a major contradiction, demanding a
radical break from 'business as usual' in the ways in which
goods (and services) are produced, distributed, and
consumed. China's growing ecological footprint is a symptom
of the predatory nature of neoliberalism and the gap it has
created between human-made and natural systems. Some 50
years back, Karl Polanyi warned that the self-regulating
market 'could not exist for any length of time without
annihilating the human and natural substance of society; it
would have physically destroyed man, and transformed his
surroundings into a wilderness'.14 It is not obvious whether
the human community is heading towards a total breakdown,
but there are signs that the current economic model is
taking us to the brink, undermining wellbeing and causing
'social recession'. Yet we have also witnessed how durable
liberal market capitalism really is. After causing a major
economic crisis, neoliberalism remains effectively
unchallenged, and the only model of economic organisation on
offer. The irony in this is that while this economic model
has lost all credibility, there appear to be no politically
durable alternatives.
As noted earlier, Africa has not benefited from
neoliberalism. On the whole, neoliberal policies
contributing to economic globalisation have reinforced the
marginalisation of African economies, which continue to
depend on a few primary goods whose prices, and market
appeal, are externally determined. Despite African
governments having obediently pursued World Bank and
International Monetary Fund (IMF) structural adjustment
programmes for nearly three decades, foreign investment in
African economies has remained negligible, and is unlikely
to be stepped up significantly in the near future. This
further hampers the participation of African countries in
the global economy as producers of goods and services. The
marginalisation of Africans as producers and consumers of
goods also means that their per capita resource use is
relatively low, which translates into low ecological and
carbon footprints. It also indicates that Africa is still
relatively unspoilt, at least when compared to other parts
of the world, where industrial footprints are much larger.
However, it also demonstrates that Africans have not
benefited from modernisation; more than 75 per cent of subSaharan
Africans do not have access to electricity, and the
performance of the health, education and water sectors is
just as poor. Some argue that Africa's energy solution lies
in opening itself to carbon trading initiatives, but even in
this respect African countries will struggle to attract
investors due to a number of practical impediments that
prevent real participation in these markets. Furthermore,
serious questions remain as to whether carbon trading is an
appropriate response to the task of climate stabilisation
and the alleviation of energy poverty more generally. The
following sections will explore these issues in greater
detail.
The place of Africa in carbon trading
The carbon market has become a multi-billion-dollar
industry, worth $144 billion in 2009 according to the World
Bank's carbon finance unit.15 It remains dominated by the
sale and re-sale of EU Allowances (EUA) under the EU's
Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS), which covers about half of
its carbon dioxide emissions. Project-based activities under
the CDM also reached the $6,5 billion mark in 2008, although
this shrank to $2,7 billion in 2009. This tailing off is
attributed to deteriorating economic conditions, coupled
with the uncertainties about post-2010 arrangements when the
Kyoto Protocol expires. According to the World Bank, China
has dominated the CDM market since its inception, accounting
for about 66 per cent of all contracted CDM supply between
2002 and 2008, and 72 per cent of the market in 2009.16
India and Brazil rank second and third on the list of
sellers in terms of volumes transacted.
Africa's share has remained at about two per cent of CDM
projects officially registered with the UN's climate change
secretariat.17 If South Africa and countries in North Africa
are taken out of the aggregate, all the other African
countries currently account for just 0.6 per cent of
registered CDM projects.18 This tiny market share has a
great deal to do with the major industrial opportunities and
low transaction costs as a result of economies of scale that
regions such as China and India are able to offer buyers of
carbon credits.19 Projects of this type include emissionssaving
technologies that may involve refitting factories to
capture or destroy industrial gases, such as HFC-23 (a
byproduct of refrigerant manufacturing, and a far more
dangerous gas than CO2), or investment in large
hydroelectricity projects that 'replace' electricity
generated by fossil fuels. Given that most sub-Saharan
African economies are largely agrarian, CDM-type investment
opportunities in large industrial gas destruction projects
are simply not available.20
Another reason why the African carbon market is less
attractive relates to how electricity is generated. Access
to electricity is a major challenge across much of Africa,
with less than 25 per cent â and, in some countries, as
little as 5 per cent â of the population enjoying access to
grid electricity.21 Thus the World Bank22 has calculated
that the 47 countries in sub-Saharan Africa, with a combined
population of 800 million people, generate as much power as
Spain, with a population of 45 million. The potential for
CDM-type projects in the power sector therefore seems
significant. However, this is complicated by the fact that
hydro power is the largest source of electricity across subSaharan
Africa by far.23
This is problematic from the perspective of carbon
accounting, given that new investment in low-carbon, gridconnected
electricity has to demonstrate that it displaces
'carbon-intensive' electricity.
The fact that large proportions of electricity are derived
from hydro sources across many countries makes it harder to
rely on 'investment' through CDM, since carbon credits would
not be awarded for proposed clean energy sources. This
obstacle was observed in the case of a recent $30 million
proposal for a 120mW wind energy scheme in northern
Ethiopia. Although the project was deemed suitable to be
registered as a CDM project, the high proportion of hydro
power resources in the country's electricity mix meant that
the emissions factor (EF)24 was relatively low. A low
emissions factor means modest corresponding Certified
Emissions Reductions (CERs),25 and therefore less money.
Given the choice, an investor seeking high returns is likely
to pick less risky but dirtier pastures elsewhere in the
South, where higher and quicker returns are guaranteed.
This 'unintended consequence', to use the World Bank's
euphemism for Africa's marginalisation,26 seems to suggest
that countries in sub-Saharan Africa are not dirty enough,
or do not consume enough, to compete successfully for
carbon-offsetting opportunities. In other words, Africa has
to get dirty to be admitted as a serious player in the CDMtype
carbon business. For the time being, the World Bank
suggests that 'African countries may do well to look even
further beyond CDM at the fast-growing carbon market in the
voluntary and retail segments',27 which may offer the
flexibility that the compliance-driven carbon market does
not.
The lack of carbon-reduction investment opportunities in the
power sector and the limited number of carbon-intensive
industries outside Northern Africa and South Africa implies
that the rest of Africa is not well positioned to influence
the direction of the debate around carbon trading.
Ultimately, carbon trading is about maximising profits by
offsetting emissions in the cheapest way possible, which
automatically favours middle-income countries that have
experienced sharp increases in energy-intensive (and carbonintensive)
industries over the past 20 years. It also means
that the market is driven by large private sector players,
with profit-seeking investors drawn to 'low-hanging' carbon
abatement opportunities. Such opportunities are hard to come
by in Africa.
The types of projects that could deliver livelihood benefits
to Africans, such as renewable and other small-scale energy
projects, are not 'cheap' options of carbon abatement, and
are therefore less likely to attract the big investors.
According to CDM Watch, as long as the CDM continues to
function as a market 'in which least-cost considerations
dominate, then it will continue to be technology-neutral,
and if there are cheaper options than renewables projects,
they will be preferred.'28 In other words, the market will
continue to favour those projects likely to deliver the
cheapest credits, and not necessarily those with the best
environmental outcomes.
This runs counter to the CDM agreement, which requires CDMtype
projects to help host countries achieve 'sustainable
development' besides helping Annex I countries to reduce
their emissions. However, because countries are allowed to
define sustainable development in their own terms, and
strike their own balance between economic fundamentals on
one hand, and equity and environmental integrity on the
other, this has been difficult to achieve. In the absence of
a universal definition that would make project overseers
more accountable for their efficacy, host country
governments are unlikely to lay down challenging sustainable
development requirements for fear of chasing away potential
investors. Hence, concerns about social and economic
inequality, which are central to the sustainable development
debate, are often treated as consequential to the single
objective of gaining carbon credits. More specific to
Africa, projects that could contribute to meeting the
Millennium Development Goals (MDGs) in respect of incomes,
education, health services, and the protection of ecosystems
are not competitive enough in terms of the CDM costeffectiveness
criteria.
Given the limited opportunities for expanding the carbon
market in Africa through the CDM, attention has shifted to
projects that can be delivered through the voluntary market.
These include improved stoves and tree planting projects,
which have been controversial for a variety of reasons,
including the difficulties they pose to verify the offsets.
The permanence of the carbon storage claimed by such
projects cannot be guaranteed, since the potential clearing
or burning of forests would return the stored carbon to the
atmosphere. There are also concerns that the fast-growing
trees favoured by project developers could threaten
biodiversity, disrupt water tables, and encourage the use of
pesticides, to the detriment of small farmers living
nearby.29 Moreover, protecting forests against loggers could
displace agricultural or logging activity to other forests â
a phenomenon known as 'activity shifting' or leakage.30
While there are many good reasons to champion forestry
programmes, notably for supporting local livelihoods as well
as the obvious contribution they make as carbon sinks,31
current tree planting practices as part of carbon offsetting
efforts conflict with the interests of local communities. A
project in the Bukaleba Forestry Reserve in Uganda, intended
to offset the GHG emissions of a coal-fired power plant to
be built in Norway, clearly illustrates the conflict of
interests of the offset company, host countries, and the
needs of local communities. The Ugandan government received
a meagre onceoff fee of US$410 and an annual rent of about
US$4,10 for each hectare of plantation, which is an absurdly
low lease price compared to the huge carbon credits the
Norwegian company (Tree Farms) was aiming to sell. The
project was also responsible for evicting 8 000 people
living on the land, depriving them of their livelihoods, and
probably driving them to clear land elsewhere. Eraker quotes
the managing director of the project as saying: 'Everyone
living and farming inside our area are illegal intruders â¦
we have told the forest authorities that this is their
responsibility.'32 What is embedded in this statement is
that tree planting under carbon trading tends to push aside
local interests, local needs and traditional land rights in
favour of external commercial interests.
Box 1: Future trends in the African carbon market Oscar
Reyes
As suggested above, Africa is currently marginal to the
carbon market, and the carbon market has been irrelevant to
the continent's efforts to address climate change. Could
this be about to change?
To start with, it is worth underscoring how little has
happened to date within the framework of the CDM. Only 6
million of the 424 million CERs (CDM credits) issued by
August 2010 have gone to African projects, and 80 per cent
of these have gone to a single industrial gas plant in
Egypt.33 Looking ahead, however, 95 new projects are seeking
approval to join the CDM (compared to the 43 already
registered). After South Africa, most of these are located
in Kenya and Uganda, with 'reforestation' projects the
largest single type requesting registration in both
countries.34 A closer look shows that these are all smallscale,
World Bank-funded schemes, though it should be noted
that the Bank has a track record of developing such
prototypes within the CDM which are then replicated on a
larger scale by the private sector, as discussed in Chapter
4.
Large-scale reforestation projects
A better indication of the shape of things to come, however,
may be a 'reforestation' project currently seeking approval
in Ghana, which would replace existing grasslands with
large-scale biodiesel monoculture plantations. The project
has been initiated by Natural African Diesel, a South
African company, which expects to receive more than 40
million CERs by 2030, and hopes it will continue to receive
credits for its plantations of jatropha and maringa at rates
of two to three million a year until 2058. However, the
biodiesel industry in Ghana has been widely criticised for
engaging in land grabs which displace local populations,
undermine food security, and fail to assess the threat that
jatropha poses to water supplies.35
Large-scale projects such as the Ghana plantations are
likely to dominate the issuance of credits â in other words,
the cash flows within the CDM.
Gas utilisation and capture projects
To date, a handful of large industrial gas projects (like
the Egyptian factory) destroying the potent greenhouse gases
HFC-23 and N2O account for almost three quarters of all
credits issued globally.36 Few such gases are produced in
Africa, but large-scale subsidies can be derived from the
CDM in other ways. Most notably, a series of new 'gas
utilisation' projects are under way in the Niger Delta. The
first of these, at Kwale, a site run by the Nigerian Agip
Oil Company (a joint venture between the Italian state oil
company Eni and its Nigerian counterpart), expects to
receive about 15 million credits by end-2016. The Pan Ocean
Gas Utilisation Project, the second such scheme to be
registered, is the largest registered CDM project in Africa,
and expects to receive more than 26 million CERs by 2020.
Shell and Chevron are developing similar projects.
There can be few clearer examples of the perverse incentives
created by the CDM. The Niger Delta projects claim to stop
gas flaring, yet this activity has already been judged
illegal by the Nigerian High Court, as also discussed in
Chapter 5. As such, companies will be rewarded for their
failure to abide by the law. Furthermore, while the projects
claim to address gas flaring, an analysis of the gases they
will process suggests that the figures are being
manipulated, and that the registered projects will process
large quantities of liquefied natural gas (LNG) and other
gases that were not associated with crude oil production in
the first place.37 In other words, these projects may be
more accurately characterised as subsidising the expansion
of fossil fuel exploitation in the Niger Delta. This, in
turn, fits into a circular structure. In the case of Kwale,
Eni's Nigerian subsidiary is locking in fossil fuel
dependence, gains credits for this activity, and sells these
to Eni in Italy. These credits will then be surrendered
within the EU ETS, enabling Eni to avoid reducing emissions
from its oil refineries in Italy. The Pan Ocean project
forms part of a similar fossil fuel cycle, with many of the
anticipated credits already purchased by Vattenfall, one of
the largest operators of coal-fired power plants in Europe.
Such circularity is not restricted to the oil and gas
sector. Most notably, the South African state-owned power
utility Eskom is conducting a feasibility study to determine
whether to seek CDM credits for Medupi, the fourth largest
coal-fired power station in the world.38 'Supercritical'
coal plants like Medupi have been eligible for CDM subsidies
since 2007.
Biomass power sector
Other large-scale opportunities are likely to exist in the
biomass power sector (which is growing rapidly within the
CDM) and hydro power sector. Such projects could fall foul
of the fact that sub-Saharan Africa is already largely
powered by hydroelectric dams, which are considered to be
zero emitting.39 However, as the example of the recently
(re)submitted Bujugali Dam in Uganda makes clear, the
comparisons used for calculating CDM baselines relate not to
existing practice but to projections of future use. Project
developers routinely maximise the projections in order to
maximise the number of available credits. In the case of
Bujugali, this is reflected in an assumption that Uganda
will be afflicted by load shedding, stimulating an increase
in the use of diesel generators and the burning of
automotive oil.40
This scenario is projected to continue indefinitely, since
the project assumes a steady issuance of credits at a rate
of 900 000 a year until 2019 (with the option of claiming
project credits for a total of 21 years).41 Needless to say,
this is highly unlikely. The financial 'additionality' of
the project is equally suspect, given that engineering for
the controversial new dam was 91 per cent complete and
procurement 99 per cent complete by the time of its
application.42
There is nothing in the CDM reform proposals currently under
discussion within UN climate talks that would put a stop to
such fanciful scenarios in claiming additionality. Nor are
these, strictly speaking, 'abuses' of the system. Such
claims about 'what would otherwise have happened' are the
very basis upon which the CDM works.
Sectoral carbon markets
Although UN climate negotiators sometimes talk the language
of environmental integrity and greater equity in offsetting,
the proposals currently on the table belie this view. The
basic premise underlying most of the proposed reforms to the
CDM, as well as potential new 'sectoral' carbon markets, is
to increase the volume of credits generated by offsetting.
This, in turn, would help industrialised countries to meet
their emissions reduction obligations without having to make
structural changes to domestic energy production, industry,
or agriculture. In other words, offsetting remains an
avoided responsibility mechanism.
There are two tracks to the UN Framework Convention on
Climate Change (UNFCCC) negotiations. The first of these is
the Ad Hoc Working Group on Further Commitments under the
Kyoto Protocol (AHG-KP), which has the remit to discuss CDM
reform. A number of proposals relate to new sectors and
industrial gases. The range of new GHG, if approved for
inclusion, would probably continue where HFC and N2O
projects left off, with the concentration of projects in
middle-income countries.
The key proposals relate to the inclusion of nuclear power
as well as carbon capture and storage (CCS) in the CDM, and
a far greater scope for agriculture and forestry projects. A
majority of developing countries continue to oppose the
proposal on nuclear power, as they feel they would have
little to gain from it. The picture is more complex with
regard to CCS which, if included, could see projects in
South Africa, where Eskom is exploring carbon capture in
coal-fired power plants; North Africa, with Algeria (which
already has its first CCS demonstration project on gas
fields run by BP and Statoil) affirming its intention of
encouraging CCS projects in CDM;43 and the gas fields of the
Niger Delta. However, serious concerns have been raised
about CCS, with UN negotiating texts including options to
exclude the technology from the CDM on the grounds of
negative environmental impacts, non-permanence of carbon
storage, potential for unforeseen leakage, measurement
difficulties, liability, safety and 'the potential for the
creation of perverse incentives for increased dependency on
fossil fuels'.44 The powerful opposition of Brazil may yet
block the inclusion of CCS in the CDM, however. In essence,
any sectoral emission reduced below a pre-set baseline would
be credited to governments.
Agriculture, forests, and Reducing Emissions from
Deforestation and Degradation (REDD)
In the case of agriculture and forests, the scope of new
measures under the CDM is vague but potentially significant,
with advocates for increasing the use of CDM in sub-Saharan
Africa identifying these sectors as potentially the most
lucrative.45
To date, afforestation/reforestation accounts for just 56 of
more than 5 300 projects being considered for inclusion in
the CDM, and no credits have yet been issued for these
projects. The slow pace in developing such projects is
partly accounted for by the availability of cheaper options,
and partly by the restrictions placed upon the use of such
credits. Such projects are currently only entitled to issue
tCERs (the 't' stands for temporary) or lCERs ('l' for longterm),
but these have proven unpopular with carbon traders,
and the prices remain low. The UNFCCC currently caps the use
of Land Use, Land Use Change and Forestry (LULUCF) credits
at one per cent of base year emissions, meaning that
industrialised countries face a limit on how many they can
buy. The EU ETS, which drives most of the demand for
offsets, currently excludes LULUCF credits altogether. And,
finally, such projects can only be developed on land that
was not forested before 1990.
While several options remain on the table, some restrictions
look set to remain â including the one per cent threshold on
such projects. However, this still provides scope for
expanding them considerably. There is significant pressure
to drop the tCER and lCER distinction, despite the fact that
the measurement difficulties that led to their creation in
the first place remain largely unresolved. The EU has
maintained the exclusion of LULUCF credits for the third
phase of its ETS (to 2020), but this provision is
potentially undermined by its intention to link its scheme
with other OECD carbon markets as those emerge. More
significantly, a series of new activities dubbed 'forest
management' could be included beyond the one per cent limit.
Under current definitions, these could include monoculture
plantations and commercial logging.46
Beyond this, a range of agricultural activities could be
included in the CDM under the rubric of 'soil management'.
While this could theoretically support small-scale, agroecological
farming â which has been shown to increase
organic matter in the soil, thereby increasing its capacity
to act as a 'sink'47 â the transaction costs and monitoring
difficulties of linking such activities to an offset scheme
would prove prohibitive. The real 'winners' from such
proposals, therefore, are likely to be in large-scale
industrial agriculture â with agribusinesses already looking
to the possibility of CDM funding for 'no-till' genetically
modified (GM) monocultures, and tree plantations to produce
biochar (a controversial technique for creating charcoal and
then burying it to 'store' carbon). In addition, the rules
on LULUCF may change to scrap the 1990 threshold, making a
far wider land area available for such projects.
In the longer term, schemes for REDD, which will begin with
public funding, are being established to kick-start a forest
carbon market capable of issuing offset credits. It is
sometimes argued that REDD, alongside the inclusion of
afforestation/reforestation of CDM, would significantly
benefit Africa on the grounds that these sectors account for
'over 60 per cent of Africa's mitigation potential'.48 Yet
the existence of considerable forested areas â including the
world's second largest forest in the Congo Basin â does not
in itself guarantee a significant flow of REDD money.
Historical deforestation rates have been far higher in
Brazil, Indonesia or Malaysia, which may be (perversely)
rewarded by REDD for having deforested more rapidly than
their African counterparts unless a 'correction factor' is
built into the scheme.49 Alternatively, the 'baselines' for
REDD could be set so high that payments will be triggered
for increases in deforestation, as is the case with a recent
agreement between Norway and Guyana.50
There are serious concerns, too, about who will benefit from
REDD, and at what environmental cost. With many forest-based
and indigenous communities having few formal titles to their
land, REDD is likely to fuel property speculation and
dispossess local populations.51 These risks are exacerbated
by the inclusion of plantations in the current UNFCCC
definition of what constitutes a forest.52 Furthermore, in
common with CDM, the complex accounting procedures involved
in commodifying forests tend to divert resources from
forestry initiatives to carbon counting. While direct
estimates for REDD are not yet available, it is reasonable
to assume that this would be comparable with the CDM, where
only 30 per cent of financing goes towards the project
itself, with the rest absorbed by consultancy fees and
taxes.53 Finally, the combination of significant
uncertainties in forest carbon accounting and weak
governance structures â such as those in the Congo Basin â
signals a capacity for large-scale fraud and the siphoning
off of funds by elite interests.54
Whether through REDD or the CDM, there is pressure to
increase the penetration of carbon markets in least
developed countries (LDCs)and in Africa in general. This is
the case both within and outside UN negotiations. At
present, the EU ETS is by far the single largest driver of
demand for CDM credits. In the absence of an international
agreement to supersede or complement the Kyoto Protocol,
whose first commitment period ends in 2012, EU policy allows
for the continued use of CDM credits on a highly selective
basis. In the absence of an international agreement, the
rules for the third phase of the EU ETS would restrict the
intake of CDM credits to projects in LDCs and Africa, and
countries that make bilateral agreements with the EU.
Increasing projects in least developed countries and Africa
In parallel, the UN negotiating texts include a proposal to
develop criteria that would increase projects in LDCs and
Africa, potentially requiring that 10 per cent of all CERs
surrendered come from these areas. While this is presented
as a progressive measure to ensure a more 'equitable'
mechanism, the nature of such projects could be
characterised as a means to share the pain of such measures
more widely: as we have seen, such projects have the
potential to stimulate land grabs, undermine food security,
and promote a model of development that keeps sub-Saharan
Africa dependent on a handful primary and extractive
industries, while most of the finance associated with the
projects flows out of the continent.
Ultimately, the political rationale for such measures lies
in a desire (advanced most forthrightly by the EC) to
advance new forms of sectoral carbon markets, targeted at
the middle-income countries currently dominating the CDM
market (including China, India, Brazil, South Korea, Mexico
and South Africa). These proposals are being developed
within the Ad Hoc Working Group on Long Term Cooperative
Action (AHG-LCA), the second track of UN climate
negotiations.55 The EC is keen to encourage these countries
to develop sector-wide carbon markets as a step on the road
to 'cap and trade' emissions trading schemes which have
binding targets on emissions. Such schemes are not proposed
as a reform or replacement to the CDM, but are envisaged as
running alongside a CDM that would be more targeted towards
LDCs and sub-Saharan Africa.
Conclusion
This discussion points to some of the practical limitations
on the benefits of carbon markets to Africa. It also alludes
to the ethical and fairness issues that are often ignored,
as though climate change can be separated from the social
and economic conditions that gave rise to it in the first
place, or the proposed solutions may in fact cause. We need
to return to the fundamental issue. The richest countries
are largely responsible for the climate problem through
their profligate burning of fossil fuels, while the effects
of climate change are disproportionately shouldered by the
poor. However, CDM and voluntary offset schemes do not
challenge the underlying consumption ethics, which continue
to drive the fossil fuel economy. If anything, offset
schemes allow industrialised countries to maintain their
affluent lifestyles by exporting the burden of reducing GHG
emissions to countries in the South, often by stressing poor
people even further. The argument that carbon trading offers
real benefits to the poor in Africa is simply not credible.
What is puzzling is the persistence of the proponents of
carbon markets, who continue to cling to these ideas in the
face of mounting evidence that carbon trading does not
deliver results commensurate to the effort invested in it.
They seem ready to 'innovate' endlessly to get a market
mechanism working because they are ideologically chained to
the 'competitiveness' agenda rather than environmental
concerns. In support of this point, Nick Davies, writing in
The Guardian, argues that carbon offsetting is
"an idea which flows not from environmentalists and climate
scientists trying to design a way to reverse global warming,
but from politicians and business executives trying to meet
the demands for action while preserving the commercial
status quo."56
Fundamental inequality is behind the climate problem, and
the search for solutions must involve industrialised
societies making fundamental structural changes to their
lifestyles, energy practices, and their production and
consumption systems.
[For notes see full pdf version available at
http://www.iss.co.za/pgcontent.php?UID=31241]
AfricaFocus Bulletin is an independent electronic
publication providing reposted commentary and analysis on
African issues, with a particular focus on U.S. and
international policies. AfricaFocus Bulletin is edited by
William Minter.
AfricaFocus Bulletin can be reached at africafocus@igc.org.
Please write to this address to subscribe or unsubscribe to
the bulletin, or to suggest material for inclusion. For more
information about reposted material, please contact directly
the original source mentioned. For a full archive and other
resources, see http://www.africafocus.org
|