African Migration, Global Inequalities, and Human Rights:
Connecting the Dots
William Minter
Nordiska Afrikainstitutet, Uppsala, 2011
Full PDF available for download at
http://nai.diva-portal.org/smash/record.jsf?pid=diva2:442755
previous section |
next section |
Table of Contents
MIGRATION AND GLOBAL INEQUALITIES
For states, the distinction between internal and
international migration is fundamental. For migrants
themselves, however, it is only one of many factors to
take into account when deciding whether to move or stay,
and where to move if the decision is made to move.
The basic dynamics of international migration involve the
same elements as internal migration: the different
opportunities that are available and known to potential
migrants, whether the migration channel is one that is
familiar and well trodden, what networks of contacts are
available to assist, the costs and risks, and the
anticipated gains. Whether migration is internal or
international, individuals, household, or extended
families do not make one single choice, but often employ
mixed strategies, including migration at different stages
of life and by different members of a household or
family.
Despite the diversity of factors involved and the
geographic dispersion of migration streams, structural
inequalities play a large role in shaping the scale and
the direction of migration everywhere. Internally
displaced people and asylum seekers move toward zones of
greater physical security. More generally, migrants move
away from regions with fewer opportunities toward regions
with more. Urbanization proceeds apace on all continents.
Within countries, zones where economic activity is waning
lose population. Across borders, the increase in
migration, although it still accounts for only 3 percent
of world population, is linked to forces that are
unlikely to be reversed.
Economist Lant Pritchett (2006: 5—7) summarizes this
convergence in what he terms "five irresistible
forces":
• Gaps in unskilled wages, often of ratios as high
as 10 to 1, between receiving and sending countries. This
compares with gaps between 2 to 1 and 4 to 1 in the 19th
century, which were themselves sufficient to induce
massive migration flows.
• Differing demographic futures, with declining
working-age populations in receiving regions such as
Europe.
• Globalization of everything except labour, as
flows of goods, capital, ideas, and communication
increase far faster than flows of people.
• Rise in employment in low-skill "non-tradable" service jobs, which cannot be outsourced
(think, for example, of trash collection), with
consequent demand for unskilled labour even in the most
advanced "world cities."
• Lagging growth in countries particularly
disadvantaged by environmental and economic shocks.
42
Scholars dispute whether or not global inequality has
increased in recent decades.23 However, there is no
dispute that the levels of global inequality are
extremely high, whether measured by income, wealth, or
more comprehensive indexes such as the Human Development
Index. Several scholars, particularly Branko Milanovic,
Roberto Korzeniewicz, and Timothy Moran, have explored
the changes in global inequality over a longer period,
and noted the implications for migration. Like class,
one's location is determined at birth. Together, notes
Milanovic (2009b: 24), class and location explain some 80
percent of income variability; other less quantifiable
factors determined at birth, such as gender, race, and
ethnicity, likely account for additional differences.
Personal effort and luck, therefore, are likely to
account for less than one-fifth of the differences in
people's incomes.
Comparing the relative contribution of class and
location, Milanovic estimates that in the early 19th
century, roughly 35 percent of differences in income was
due to differences between countries, while some 65
percent was due to within-country differences. In the
early 21st century, the proportions were more than
reversed, with 85 to 90 percent due to differences
between countries and 10 to 15 percent due to within-country differences. Over the same period, the overall
level of global inequality grew from a Gini index of 43
(slightly more equal than the 45 Gini index for the
United States) to a Gini index of 70, This is a higher
level of inequality than the 65 Gini index for South
Africa, which is among the highest in the world.
Scholars will continue to debate the precise numbers in
such estimates, which are at best rough approximations.
However, the importance of place of birth as a
determinant of one's life chances is an unavoidable
conclusion once one begins to consider global
stratification rather than only stratification within
countries. The difference in wages and other
opportunities between countries holds not only for
unskilled labour but at almost all levels of the
occupational and social ladder, with the exception of the
"super-rich" (many of whom have residences and
other assets spread among multiple countries). The
result, note Korzeniewicz and Moran (2009: 101) is that:
From a global perspective, there are three main paths to
social mobility: (1) a change (up or down) in the
relative position of individuals or groups within
national income distributions; (2) a change in the
relative position of nations within the international
income distribution; or (3) a shift in the relative
location of individuals or groups within the global
distribution of income attained through categorical
mobility [i.e. moving from one country to another].
23. See Milanovic (2005) for a review of the issues,
which include measurement questions, as well as the
specific role of large countries such as India and China.
43
But the third option should be considered not as movement
from one closed box to another, but as part of a
continuum. Table 7, adapted from Korzeniewicz and Moran,
is helpful in envisaging a more nuanced set of
alternatives, arranging income deciles from 85 countries
on one global scale.24 Looking at the table, one can see
how industrialized countries are concentrated in the
upper deciles and African countries in particular
concentrated in the lower deciles. The highest (10th)
decile for Nigeria, Kenya, and Burkina Faso, for example,
is located in the 7th global decile. It is below the
lowest (1st) decile in the United States, Italy,
Australia, and many other industrialized countries, which
are located globally in the 9th global decile.
pdf of Table 7.
A simplistic "push-pull" model might lead one
to think that the poorest people would be the most likely
to migrate from one country to another. But in fact
migration, whether internal and international, requires
resources; witness those left behind in New Orleans
during the Hurricane Katrina disaster. The sharp
inequality between countries makes moving internationally
an attractive alternative particularly for those who are
already mobile geographically and economically within
their countries. Their contacts and other resources make
such a choice feasible.
For African migrants, as for migrants in most cases
around the world, those who migrate are predominantly not
the poorest but those who are well enough off to afford
the costs of moving, but who find themselves unemployed,
underemployed, or lacking opportunities to improve their
living conditions. And most take the initiative
themselves, rather than being recruited by smugglers.
While they may make use of agents to pass particularly
difficult borders, migrants themselves are the ones who
put the pieces together for complex and often multi-stage
migration journeys. International migration, just as
internal migration from countryside to city or from
poorer areas to richer ones, is one of the repertoire of
options that people use to improve their opportunities
and the opportunities of their families.
The parallel between the forces at work in internal and
international migration can also be seen by analysing
systems in which states have attempted to control
internal migration by imposing internal borders and
restrictions of movement. The most notorious example, of
course, is the South African apartheid system. That
system is often envisaged merely as a system of racial
separation. But it was also an elaborately constructed
system of labour control, as "pass laws"
defined the rights of Africans to live and work in
specific areas. Workers on temporary contracts but
without rights were channelled to places where labour was
needed, to be used and then returned to
"homelands" and neighbour-
24. For comparison, average income has been added in
brackets for a number of countries for which decile data
is not available.
44
47
ing countries. Workers with special skills were given
more permanent rights to reside in urban areas, albeit
without political rights. But even the force of the
apartheid state at its height and regular removals of
"surplus people" were insufficient to stop
migration.
The less well known "hukou" system in China,
intended to limit rural to urban migration, also
illustrates how geographic inequality drives migration
even when restrictions on movement are enforced by legal
barriers (UNDP 2009: 52; Chan and Buckingham 2008;
Amnesty International 2007). Although the system, which
allocates rights to employment, housing, and social
services, has become more flexible in recent decades, and
additional reforms are being discussed, it is still the
case that almost all internal migrants lack full rights
in urban areas. A significant proportion of migrants lack
proper documentation for temporary residence, risking
arrest, imprisonment, or deportation to their home areas.
In Africa and around the world, use of coercion to
control internal population movement and settlement has
proved ineffective, even when it includes such drastic
measures as slum clearance and forced evictions. Instead,
it has heightened vulnerability of migrants and
reinforced inequalities both within and between
geographic areas. For international migration, likewise,
despite the political appeal of more restrictive measures
in many receiving countries, the promise of
"control" is likely to be elusive. Such
measures may well raise the cost and risk of migration,
shift migration from regular to irregular channels, or
divert migrants from one destination country to another.
They certainly tend to increase the scale of human rights
abuses against migrants. What they will not do is to stop
the trend of increasing migration in an unequal world,
any more than internal controls have stopped rural to
urban migration within countries.
The option of reducing migration by promoting development
in countries of origin may be more sensitive to human
rights concerns and may bring benefits to developing
countries. But it is unlikely to succeed on a sufficient
scale to reduce migration. It may even increase it, by
increasing the proportion of persons in developing
countries with sufficient assets to move. This option
also fails to question the assumption that migration in
itself is a problem. While it may provide an attractive
option for receiving and sending countries, it fails to
address the rights of migrants and potential migrants.
Seeking "win-win-win" alternatives, as
suggested by the 2009 Human Development Report, is by no
means an easy quest. But one prerequisite is to shift the
focus away from seeing migration itself as the problem.
By recognizing migration as an indispensable component of
human freedom and human development, one can reduce the
chances that migration, whether internal or
international, will be accompanied by human rights
abuses, conflicts of interest, and reinforcement of
hostile stereotypes.
48
If migration itself is seen as the problem, migrants will
inevitably be the victims of policies to reduce
migration, as successive control measures fail.
"Win-win-win" migration, on the other hand,
implies goals that may be difficult but are not
inherently impossible. Potential migrants should not be
forced to remain in an area, nor be compelled by
unbearable circumstances to leave, but should be able to
make real choices to go or to stay. Emigration should not
drain the sending country of human resources, and
immigration should not increase inequality and social
conflict within the receiving country. Reducing migration
that has such negative effects is no less complicated a
goal than reducing migration as such. But it is one which
does not deny the reality that migration will continue.
The problem is not migration as such, but inequalities in
human development and in access to fundamental human
rights, both within and between societies. The following
sections explore issues that arise from such an
alternative framework. In considering the relationship
between migration and development, for example, the issue
is not only the development of the societies of origin,
but the human development of migrants themselves and
equitable relationships between societies of origin and
destination. Understanding the nexus between migration
and human rights requires addressing not only the rights
of migrants but also universal human rights, which apply
to all persons regardless of their location, citizenship,
or legal status. And the topic of advocacy agendas
addresses the extraordinarily difficult question of how
to increase the chances that "win-win-win"
migration agendas can gain traction within highly
unfavourable political and public opinion climates in
countries of destination.
49
|