African Migration, Global Inequalities, and Human Rights:
Connecting the Dots
William Minter
Nordiska Afrikainstitutet, Uppsala, 2011
Full PDF available for download at
http://nai.diva-portal.org/smash/record.jsf?pid=diva2:442755
previous section |
next section |
Table of Contents
MIGRATION AND DEVELOPMENT
Although the development debate continues to focus on
macroeconomic growth, as well as on achievement of anti-poverty targets such as the Millennium Development Goals,
over two decades the annual UNDP human development
reports have encouraged expansion of the range of
objectives to consider (http://
hdr.undp.org/en/reports/). The 2009 Human Development
Report, focusing on migration, laid out an agenda to
enhance human development outcomes for movers and for
countries of origin and destination. The 2010 Human
Development Report, concentrating on inequality within
countries, made the case that internal inequality in
itself impedes human development.25
This brief review of specific issues related to migration
and development offers no new policy solutions. The
objective is rather to illustrate how a human development
framework, combined with consideration of global
inequalities, can provide a broader context for policy
debate. Developing "win-win-win" policies on
migration requires building a consensus in favour of
"inequality-reducing" human development. In
short, development should be redistributive, both
globally and within countries.
The challenge of measuring global inequality, or other
inequalities based on units other than countries is, of
course, substantial, since statistics are based on
national boundaries. Thus one can relatively easily
generate measures within a specific country or between
countries. But finding comparable measures for groups
that overlap country borders, such as people born in a
specific country (including those now in the diaspora),
is more difficult. Nevertheless, the first step is to
call attention to the need to do so. Migration systems
and networks, as well as specific processes such as the
transfer of remittances, operate both within and across
national boundaries. In order to understand the dynamics
at work, it is important to consider the wider set of
relationships, including inequalities, between sending
countries and receiving countries. Thus, whether in
binational or multinational terms, one might advance
migration within the broader policy goals of reducing
inequalities. One might develop a measure of inequality
across the countries within a migration system, such as
Western Europe-North Africa, or within the Southern
African region, combining within-country and between-country inequality as in the measures of global
inequality discussed above.
Or, while maintaining the focus on a particular sending
country, one could develop measures of "income per
natural" as well as "income per resident."
As
25. Although they confine their study to developed
countries, comparing countries as well as states within
the United States, Wilkinson and Pickett (2009) in The
Spirit Level make a strong case that inequality has
multiple negative effects not only for those on the
bottom ranks but also for human development outcomes for
other societal strata and for society as a whole.
50
advanced by Clemens and Pritchett (2008), such a measure
would look at the income for the population born in a
specific country, including both residents and migrants
living outside the country. Such a measure might
indicate, as Clemens and Pritchett argue, that migration
is one of the most important means of poverty reduction
for a large portion of the developing world. Crossing
international boundaries, they argue, is not an
"alternative" to development; it is in fact one
of the components of development, significantly raising
the average income of the set of persons born in a
specific country.
Despite the greater difficulty of collecting data that
goes beyond the framework of national borders, placing
internal and international migration within the same
framework is a logical next step in examining such
current topics as remittances, brain drains/gains, and
the role of diaspora populations within overall human
development strategies.26
Remittances
Since the World Bank's focus on the issue in Global
Economic Prospects 2006, remittances have become part of
the mainstream discussion on development. The most recent
estimates from the World Bank (2010) note that recorded
remittances to developing countries worldwide will
recover to $325 billion in 2010, up from $307 billion in
2009, and may even exceed $370 billion by 2012. Despite
declines due to the world economic crisis, remittances
were more resilient than other financial flows, and
remained almost three times greater than official
development assistance (ODA) to developing countries.
Flows to Sub-Saharan Africa were estimated at a stable
$21 billion a year from 2008 to 2010, and projected to
increase to $24 billion in 2012. In contrast to the
global picture, totals for recorded remittances to Africa
were not greater than flows of ODA. According to the
World Bank, the top five remittance-receiving countries
were Nigeria ($10.0 billion), Sudan ($3.2 billion), Kenya
($1.8 billion), Senegal ($1.2 billion), and South Africa
($1.0 billion). In terms of remittances as a percentage
of gross domestic product (GDP), the top five were
Lesotho (24.8%), Togo (10.3%), Cape Verde (9.1%), Guinea-Bissau (9.1%), and Senegal (9.1%). In North Africa,
grouped with the Middle East in World Bank data, the top
remittance-receiving countries were Egypt ($7.7 billion),
Morocco ($6.4 billion), Algeria ($2.0 billion), and
Tunisia ($2,0 billion). As a percentage of GDP,
remittances were highest in Morocco (6.6%), Tunisia
(5.3%), Egypt (4.0%), and Algeria (1.4%).27
26. For an extensive review of current policy
debates on these specific issues, and more current
statistics, published too late to the new data be
incorporated systematically into this essay, see Ratha
et al. (2011).
27. But, notes the World Bank (2009a: 8), remittance
data for Sub-Saharan Africa is thought to be even less
reliable than in other world regions. Flows are probably
substantially higher than reported.
51
There is a growing consensus in current research and
policy debate that remittances should not be seen as
substitutes for other sources of national financing, such
as development assistance or foreign investment. Their
economic contribution, channelled principally to direct
family needs, is valuable in its own right, not only for
the individuals and households receiving it but for
national economies. As part of their mixed strategies for
survival and advancement, households often combine
international remittances with those from family members
working in urban areas in the home country.28 It follows
that attempts to tax remittances or to channel them into
development projects are likely to be less effective,
from a national development standpoint, than helping
households access and invest these remittances for their
own survival and betterment, including in health and
education.
The costs of sending remittances, which go principally
through money transfer operators rather than through the
banking system, are high. Although transmission costs
have decreased somewhat worldwide, from 9.8% for a $200
transfer in last quarter of 2008 to 8.9% in the first
quarter of 2010, the reduction was principally in the
U.S./Mexico corridor, with rates remaining high in
Africa.29 Substantial savings could be achieved by
introducing greater competition into the system, and a
Global Remittances Working Group initiated by the G8
countries in 2008 has called for reducing the cost by 5
percentage points over five years. By requiring providers
of remittance services to be more transparent about fees,
the Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act,
signed into U.S. law in 2010, has the potential to give
greater leverage to remitters. But the global remittance
market is still dominated by large players such as
Western Union and MoneyGram, which face little
competition in many smaller markets.
While greater competition may bring about incremental
reductions in remittance costs, the extent of competition
also depends on the size of the national markets and the
extent of government initiatives specifically aimed at
promoting lower costs. According to the World Bank, Sub-Saharan Africa has the highest average cost among
regions, at 11.57% in the third quarter of 2010.
A promising advance in some African countries is the
introduction of money transfer via mobile phone,
beginning with M-Pesa in Kenya. This trend is likely to
continue. But it has as yet had little impact on
transfers across national borders. If regulatory barriers
could be overcome, this technology could have a very
substantial competitive impact on lowering international
remittance costs as well, particularly between
neighbouring countries within Africa.
With continued emphasis from the World Bank and related
agencies, remit-
28. See, for example, the study of Ghanaian migrant
networks by Valentina Mazzucato, in DeWind and Holdaway
2008: 71-102.
29. For regularly updated data, see the World Bank's
database on remittance prices (http://remittanceprices.worldbank.org/).
52
tances are likely to receive sustained policy attention.
However, it is still important to contextualize these
financial flows with respect to other flows, in order to
evaluate their potential impact on development. These
other flows include not only foreign investment, official
development assistance, and trade balances, but also the
very substantial illicit financial flows, which are even
less well tracked than remittances and only now beginning
to attract more systematic international attention.30
The reforms needed for accurate reporting of data of
illicit financial flow are daunting. They include
transparency on country-by-country accounts of
multinational corporations, documentation of the true
residence of beneficiaries of banking accounts, and
exchange of tax information between governments in the
case of suspicious transactions. In contrast to
remittances, however, the amounts involved in individual
transactions are likely to be substantial. In looking at
the results for inequality within and between countries,
and among those born in a country (including diasporas),
such flows should also become an essential part of the
migration and development debate.
Brain Drains and Gains
The "brain drain," or loss of skilled workers
through emigration, has long been the subject of policy
debate and development research. It has also received
significant attention in the media. The migration of
health workers is particularly visible, with large
numbers of foreign doctors and nurses working in
developed countries while health crises grip African and
other developing countries.31
Nevertheless, despite a significant body of research,
reliable data are elusive, and effective solutions even
more so.32 For Africa, where the total rate of emigration
was 1.8% in 2000, the rate of emigration of high-skilled
workers was more than five times greater, at 10.4%
(Marfouk 2007: 17). Twenty-five African countries had
high-skilled emigration rates of 15% or more. The top ten
were Cape Verde (67%), The Gambia (63%), Mauritius (56%),
Seychelles (56%), Sierra Leone (53%), Ghana (47%),
Mozambique (45%), Liberia (45%), Kenya (38%), and Uganda (36%).
The largest absolute number of high-skilled emigrants
came
30. In recent studies, Global Financial Integrity
(http://www.gfif.org) has begun efforts to estimate these
flows. According to this nongovernmental organization,
illicit capital flows worldwide from crime, corruption,
and trade mispricing amounted to some $1.26 trillion in
2008, having increased by 18% a year since 2000 from a
base figure of $369.3 billion. Illicit financial flows
out of Africa were estimated at %63.8 billion in 2008,
including some $37 billion from Nigeria alone (Global
Financial Integrity 2010, 2011).
31. For recent sources on health worker migration
see http://www.guardian.co.uk/global-health-workers,
http://www.who.int/hrh/migration/en, and
http://www.who.int/workforcealli-ance/en/.
32. For data sources, see particularly Docquier
(2007), Docquier and Marfouk (2006), and the online
datasets at
http://perso.uclouvain.be/frederic.docquier/oxlight.htm.
Summary statistics for African skilled migration, as of
2000, are in Marfouk (2007).
53
from countries with larger populations, including South
Africa (168,000), Nigeria (149,000), Egypt (149,000),
Morocco (141,000), and Algeria (86,000).
The losses to sending countries from emigration of
skilled emigrants, particularly in the cases of smaller
and least developed countries, are clear. In recent
years, some scholars have also pointed to "brain
gain" effects, such as remittances, return migration
of migrants with added skills, diaspora contributions to
development, and the effect of the opportunity for
overseas education and employment in increasing
incentives for professional education in sending
countries. It is generally agreed, however, that these
positive effects are unlikely to be sufficient to
compensate for negative effects in most developing
countries.33
The most extensive policy debate on skilled migration has
dealt with health workers. However, there is now a
growing consensus that the principal responses to date
have been ineffective.34 These include measures to
prohibit migration of skilled workers (not only
ineffective but also in violation of the rights of
migrants themselves) or to pay incentives for return (of
limited effectiveness). Most widely discussed has been
the development of voluntary codes of conduct,
culminating in the World Health Assembly's adoption of
the "WHO Global Code of Practice on the
International Recruitment of Health Personnel"
(WHA63.16, 21 May 2010).
Even when voluntary codes are adopted, however, they face
a policy climate in developed countries which
systematically encourages the immigration of skilled
labour. Moreover, professionals continue to be attracted
by the higher salaries and generally better working
conditions in the rich countries. In the health field, it
is unlikely that brain drain issues can be addressed
effectively without broad international cooperation to
reduce inequality in health systems and health outcomes
between countries. The shortage of health personnel in
developed as well as developing countries needs to be met
through an expansion of education and training capacity,
both overall and in the most disadvantaged countries in
particular. Global health budgets need to be provided
with sustainable financing from both national and
international sources, including new innovative financing
mechanisms such as those being developed by UNITAID.
In short, the perspective needs to shift to the
development of health systems rather than focusing only
on the migration of health workers. The supply of health
workers is just one of multiple factors affecting health
systems equity. Promoting quality health systems both
requires and attracts skilled health professionals. If
that is accepted as the shared goal, both at national and
international levels and by health institutions and
professionals themselves, then distribution
33. See Docquier (2007) and several chapters in
Ozden and Schiff (2006).
34. See, in particular, Physicians for Human Rights
(2004), Mensah, Mackintosh, and Henry (2005), and Khadria
(2010).
54
of personnel to meet the needs can be addressed—not only
by encouraging return of skilled professionals to their
countries of origin, but also by more flexible forms of
temporary assignment and collaboration across national
lines.
International coordination in planning for human
resources in health, including these and other measures,
has recently taken significant steps forward with the
first Global Forum on Human Resources for Health, held in
2008 in Kampala, Uganda, and the second, which took place
in Bangkok, Thailand, in January 2011. The forums are
managed by a multi-stakeholder Global Health Workforce
Alliance (http://www.who.int/workforcealliance/en/). They
aim to address the worldwide shortage of health workers,
estimated at 4.2 million, with 1.5 million needed in
Africa alone. The Alliance has identified 57 countries
that urgently need additional human resources to meet
health crises, of which 39 are in Africa.
African Union Draft Strategic Framework on Migration in
Africa: Suggested Actions on Brain Drain
• Counter the exodus of skilled nationals by
promoting the NEPAD strategy for retention of Africa's
human capacities; targeting economic development
programmes to provide gainful employment, professional
development and educational opportunities to qualified
nationals in their home countries.
• Counter the effects of "brain drain" by
encouraging nationals abroad to contribute to the
development of their country of origin through financial
and human capital transfers such as short and long term
return migration, the transfer of skills, knowledge and
technology including in the context of programmes such as
the IOM MIDA (Migration in Development for Africa)
Programme, and activities of ILO, WHO and other relevant
agencies.
• Foster private sector opportunities to provide
alternative employment to the low paying public sector
and reduce brain drain
• Member States establish policies for the
replacement of qualified persons who have left the
country of origin and implement retention policies and
related strategies.
• Maximize the contribution of skilled professionals
in the continent by facilitating mobility and deployment
of professionals in a continental and regional framework
African Union (2005: 27)
In other areas of the economy, as in health, actions on
brain drain should not be aimed at reducing mobility but
rather at flexibly integrating professional development
and employment within broader development strategies.
Consensus around goals such as those laid out by the
African Union (see box) is growing. The UNDP's TOKTEN
(Transfer of Knowledge through Expatriate Nationals)
program, established in 1977, is being joined by a host
of parallel efforts, such as
55
the World Bank's African Diaspora Program. Their success,
however, is likely to depend primarily on the progress of
development in specific sectors and specific countries.35
Diasporas and Development
While policy debates on the specific topics of
remittances and brain drain are most advanced, there is
also growing interest in the overall role of diasporas in
development. Topics include the role of migrant
organizations in "co-development" projects,
investment of capital from the diaspora both directly and
through mechanisms such as "diaspora bonds,"
and, more generally, the need for governments to create
structures to actively involve emigrant communities in
national development. Given the heterogeneity of
diasporas and country situations, however, the
development of general lessons has been limited and is
likely to remain so.36
The priorities for governments and agencies in countries
of origin and in host countries should be to recognize
the diversity of diaspora-initiated activities under way
and selectively foster those with the greatest benefits
for development, rather than attempting to bring them all
under one umbrella. Examples of African countries which
have taken significant steps in this direction are
Morocco and Cape Verde. Mali has established a Ministry
for Malians Abroad and African Integration; it also
provides representation for Malians abroad in government
institutions, and allows dual citizenship.37 In the
Moroccan diaspora the nongovernmental organization
Migrations et Developpement has established a solid track
record of accomplishment (Ould Aoudia 2010). AFFORD UK
(http://www.afford-uk.org) has worked for more than a
decade to encourage involvement of Africans in the United
Kingdom in development on the African continent, and the
Eunomad networks (http://www.eunomad.org), founded in
2007, are now functional in nine European countries.
There are a host of both formal and informal diaspora
organizations for almost every country, at multiple
levels.38 But most are documented only sporadically.
Unlike the topic of
35. Among the most promising, which can be
implemented at multiple levels, are programs for
collaboration between universities. See, for recent
reports, focused on Europe and Africa in particular, the
program co-sponsored by the European University
Association, the Association of African Universities, and
related groups (http://www.accesstosuccess-africa.eu).
36. For a clear analysis, see de Haas (2006a). Other
recent reviews of the literature include Agunias (2009),
Pastore (2007), and Ionescu (2006). Eunomad (2010)
provides a review of practices of co-development in 9
European countriees.
37. For more examples of African government diaspora
programs, see Ratha et al. (2011: 177—179.)
38. As one example, see the Eko Club International
network of Lagosians in the diaspora, with chapters in
North America and Europe which support medical and
educational projects in Lagos
(http://ekoklubinternational.com).
56
remittances, the impact of diaspora organizations is one
on which there is still very little systematic data.
There is little doubt that "migration and
development" is well on the way to becoming an
established item on the development agenda and in
negotiations between countries of origin and destination.
But, except in the specific areas of remittances and
brain drain, the prospects for new policy developments
still seem limited. Scholars and many officials recognize
the self-defeating danger in linking development aid to
pressure for more restrictions on migration, and the
folly of assuming that development will reduce migration.
Yet such perspectives are strongly entrenched. And
development policies involving diasporas are subject to
the same constraints as development policies more
generally. Just as the prospects for development depend
on the wider political context in both developing and
developed countries, the potential role of diasporas
depends on where they are placed with respect to the
political and economic structures in both societies.
For example, options such as voting abroad and dual
citizenship have been applauded as increasing the
opportunities for continued diaspora involvement in
countries such as Ghana, yet they are inextricably
entangled with political divisions in most national
contexts in Africa. The multiple roles of the diaspora
are certainly significant in cases such as Zimbabwe,
Eritrea, or Nigeria, for example. But the options for
their involvement in development depends above all on the
broader political and social context of which they are a
part. The nature of their involvement also depends on
whether diaspora groups are committed to inequality-reducing development or are linked primarily to
privileged class networks within their country of origin.
In destination countries, the option of adopting
migration policies that contribute to human development
is severely constrained by political realities. In its
chapter laying out policies to "enhance human
development outcomes" from migration, the 2009 Human Development Report (UNDP 2009:
95-112) includes "liberalizing and simplifying
regular channels that allow people to seek work
abroad." It cautiously suggests not only
regularizing the status of irregular migrants but also
expanding the number of visas for unskilled workers. The
report also suggests, but does not fully elaborate, the
concept of human development of peoples (UNDP 2009: 14;
Ortega 2009), measuring human development not by country
of current residence but by country of origin.
In these terms, as explained most fully by Lant Pritchett
in Let Their People Come (Pritchett 2006), the most
effective action developed countries could take for
development would be to open their borders more widely,
particularly for unskilled immigrants, who both gain
substantially themselves by migration and are most likely
to maintain family connections with those most in need in
their countries of origin. The trend in immigration
policy, however, is precisely
57
the reverse: countries increasingly favour skilled
migrants. Pritchett proposes expanding strictly defined
temporary contract migration, as in the Gulf Cooperation
Council states, to counter policy opposition to such
measures. But that begs the question of the difficulty of
protecting the rights of migrants and increasing
inequality within destination states. The political
feasibility of these or other measures for regularizing
and expanding mobility to promote development will
depend, it is clear, on fundamental changes in public
understandings of both the rights of migrants and the
right to migrate. That is the subject of the next section
of this essay.
58
|